FIRST-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION: A form of price discrimination in which a seller charges the highest price that buyers are willing and able to pay for each quantity of output sold. This is also termed perfect price discrimination because the seller is able to extract ALL consumer surplus from the buyers. This is one of three price discrimination degrees. The others are second-degree price discrimination and third-degree price discrimination.As the alternative name "perfect" suggests, this is the ultimate in price discrimination. It is price discrimination to which price discriminators aspire, but seldom if ever achieved in the real world. To accomplish first-degree price discrimination, a seller needs to know the highest demand price that every buyer is willing and able to pay for each quantity purchased. Such information is seldom available. Three ConditionsTo be a successful price discriminator, a seller must satisfy three things: (1) to have market control and be a price maker, (2) to identify different prices that different buyers are willing to pay, and (3) to keep the buyers from reselling the good. In this way, a seller is able to charge each buyer the maximum price.
A Different Price for EveryoneFirst-degree price discrimination can be illustrated using the accompanying diagram. The demand curve displayed here is that facing Feet-First Pharmaceutical, a well-known monopolist that controls the market for Amblathan-Plus, the only cure for the deadly (but hypothetical) foot ailment known as amblathanitis.
Ignoring this bit of realism, how would Feet-First Pharmaceutical pursue first-degree price discrimination? This is accomplished by moving down the demand curve, identifying the maximum price for each quantity, then charging this price.
Of course, the amount of information needed by the seller can be quite extensive. Most firms that seek to undertake price discrimination have more than a handful of buyers. They are likely to face thousands, hundreds of thousands, or even millions of buyers, each willing and able to pay a different price. Marginal RevenueThe first of two interrelated implications resulting from first-degree price discrimination involves the relation between marginal revenue, average revenue, and demand. Because a first-degree price-discriminating seller charges the maximum demand price for each unit sold, the demand curve facing the firm is also the marginal revenue curve. The demand curve reflects the incremental change in revenue. But if the demand curve is marginal revenue, it cannot be average revenue, too.An average revenue curve does exist, it is just not the demand curve as is the case for other firms. It is related to the price-discrimination-based marginal revenue curve in the same way that any average is related to its corresponding marginal. The marginal lies below the average when the average is declining. As such, the average revenue curve lies above this marginal revenue curve. Compare this with the demand, average revenue, and marginal revenue relation for a "normal" monopoly. The demand curve and average revenue curve are one and the same and the marginal revenue curve lies below the demand/average revenue curve. EfficiencyThe second implication resulting from first-degree price discrimination involves to efficiency. A monopoly firm that practices first-degree price discrimination actually achieves an efficient allocation of resources. Ironically, what appears to be inefficiency compounded with inefficiency results in an efficient allocation of resources. Monopoly is bad. Price discrimination is bad. Together they are efficient. How so?The key rests with the profit-maximizing equality between marginal revenue and marginal cost. A non-discriminating monopoly equates marginal revenue to marginal cost and charges a price that is greater than marginal cost. This is not efficient. A first-degree price-discriminating monopoly also maximizes profit by equating marginal revenue to marginal cost. The difference, however, is that price is equal to marginal cost for the discriminating seller. As such, the profit-maximizing decision to equate marginal revenue and marginal cost results in the equality between price and marginal cost--which is the key criterion for efficiency. Of course, even though efficiency is achieved, there is an equity downside. Every bit of consumer surplus generated by buyers is transferred to the monopoly seller. Society gains with an efficient allocation of resources. The monopoly seller gains with profit. But buyers lose with less consumer surplus. The Other Two DegreesFirst-degree price discrimination is one of three forms of price discrimination. The other two are second-degree and third-degree.
Check Out These Related Terms... | price discrimination | second-degree price discrimination | third-degree price discrimination | Or For A Little Background... | monopoly | market control | perfect competition | price elasticity of demand | consumer surplus | demand | demand curve | demand price | marginal revenue | marginal revenue curve | marginal cost | marginal cost curve | profit maximization | efficiency | equity | And For Further Study... | perfect competition, profit maximization | monopoly, profit maximization | Recommended Citation: FIRST-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION, AmosWEB Encyclonomic WEB*pedia, http://www.AmosWEB.com, AmosWEB LLC, 2000-2025. [Accessed: January 27, 2025]. |